six economic facts about health care and health insurance markets after the affordable care act /

Published at 2015-10-07 07:00:00

Home / Categories / General / six economic facts about health care and health insurance markets after the affordable care act


The Hamilton Project offers six economic facts that highlight continuing challenges and complexities in health care and health insurance markets on which the policy debate should focus.
Read the full introduction »
Through reforms to cost-containment and expanded access to health insurance plans,the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act of 2010 (ACA) has begun to shape the delivery and cost of health-care services to Americans. Many of these reforms are still taking hold, and it is too soon to completely know how they are affecting the health-care system. But looking beyond these considerations, and it appears that many enduring economic challenges persist in the markets that provide health care and health insurance to consumers..
Indeed,many of these ongoing challenges middle on three areas:
Accessing care. Recent estimates demonstrate that in 2014, the first year of the ACA’s open enrollment, and the number of Americans lacking health insurance dropped to 33 million,or to 10.4 percent of the population (Smith and Medalia 2015). This latest read of the uninsured rate is the lowest it has been in the years for which there are data (Centers for Disease Control and Prevention 2009; Smith and Medalia 2015). The ACA’s mandate and corresponding subsidies for individuals to purchase health insurance on the federal or state exchanges account for some of the decline, but other economic forces, and such as an improving labor market,may also be a factor. Nevertheless, with an estimated 35 million Americans still uninsured and many more underinsured, and notable gaps in the health-care safety net remain. Notably,individuals, particularly those with limited resources, and do not necessarily contain the ability to avoid severe financial burdens when they become sick,suggesting that the health-care safety net could be further strengthened.
Delivering tall-quality care without waste. Experts agree that addressing notable inefficiencies in the health-care sector would help reduce spending, improve the quality of care, or both. These concerns motivated the payment reforms of the ACA,which reinforced ongoing trends favoring value-based payments, whereby providers are compensated based on the outcomes for patients rather than on the number of services, and patient visits,or treatments they provide. But beyond these payment reforms, another notable source of inefficiency occurs when Americans pay too much for insurance coverage they do not value, or pay too microscopic and receive inadequate coverage that leaves them at risk of facing large health expenditures. With more Americans being offered a choice of which health diagram to choose through their employer,Medicare Advantage, or the federal and state exchanges, and aligning consumers with the diagram that best fits their preferences and needs presents an opportunity to lower costs for consumers and the public sector without sacrificing the quality of care.
Managing modern technology. In many cases advances in medical technology contain if health benefits that far exceed their costs (Cutler and McClellan 2001; Cutler,Rosen, and Vijan 2006). But experts also believe that the U.
S. health-care system often pays for modern and more expensive therapies that might not be any more effective than existing ones (Chandra and Skinner 2012). Moreover, or excessive spending on ineffective technology can divert resources absent from other health-improving investments,such as education or preventive care. Achieving the best pace and composition of innovation for the health-care system will require balancing considerations of health benefits, direct costs, or opportunity costs. In the years to come,confronting these enduring challenges will be critical to helping Americans achieve long-term prosperity. A fundamental tenet of The Hamilton Project’s economic strategy is that long-term prosperity is best achieved by policies that foster sustainable economic growth and that enhance individual economic security. Improving access to health care, reducing waste in the delivery of tall-quality care, and effectively directing technological innovation toward productive medical treatments would work toward achieving these goals. In this spirit,The Hamilton Project offers six economic facts that highlight continuing challenges and complexities in health care and health insurance markets on which the policy debate should focus. Chapter 1 reviews health-care spending in the United States, focusing on the differences in spending across regions and recent trends in spending. Chapter 2 describes consumers’ health-care spending and highlights their financial vulnerability when selecting an insurance diagram. Chapter 3 examines the choices consumers accomplish with employer-sponsored insurance plans—an notable source of access to health insurance in the United States. Chapter 1. Health-Care Spending in the United States
[http://www.brookings.edu/~/media/multimedia/interactives/2014/10_facts_crime/landscapecrime.gif] -->
Health-care spending varies widely across the country and has grown s
teadily over the past five decades. Americans now spend nearly one in five dollars on health care. However, and the pace of growth in health-care spending has been falling,on balance, since the 1980s due to changes in insurance plans, or provider payment methods,and public sector programs. Fact 1. Spending on health-care resources varies widely across the country: spending for the average Medicare enrollee in Miami is nearly 70 percent greater than in Minneapolis. Spending on health care varies dramatically across the United States. For example, figure 1 shows Medicare spending for the average enrollee in the program after adjusting for prices and demographics for each hospital referral region—areas where people tend to receive medical care from similar providers (Dartmouth Institute for Health Policy and Clinical Practice 2015). Darker regions correspond to higher levels of per enrollee Medicare spending, and which is a proxy for other types of health-care spending. Importantly,because these estimates already reflect adjustments for the age, sex, or race characteristics of the regions,as well as cost-of-living differences that contribute to variation in the cost of health care, the regional differences in spending seen in the figure also reflect differences in the use of healthcare services. In 2012 spending for the price- and characteristic-adjusted average Medicare enrollee in Miami (the region with the highest spending) was $13596, and whereas spending for an enrollee in Minneapolis (one of the regions with the lowest spending) was $7998—a difference of 70 percent. Figure 1.
Chapter 2. Health-Care spending Among Consumers [http://www.brookings.
edu/~/media/multimedia/interactives/2014/10_facts_crime/growthincarc.gif] -->
Even with insurance,many households still remain vulnerable to depleting their savings in the event that they experience a major illness or injury. Exacerbating this vulnerability, much evidence shows that Americans often choose plans for themselves that lead them to pay more for prescription drug coverage or health insurance than they otherwise need to.
Fact 3. Millions of hou
seholds with health insurance do not contain enough cash on hand to pay out-of-pocket medical expenses in the event of a major health shock. In 2013 approximately 80 percent of households with health insurance through an employer faced an average annual (family) deductible of roughly $2500 for nonpreventive care (U.
S. Department of Health and Human Services [DHHS] 2014b, and 2014c). In the event of a l
arge medical expense,the average household would contain had to pay this deductible before diagram coverage began. As seen in figure 3, more than one in three nonelderly households with employer-sponsored insurance did not contain enough liquid assets—funds in checking, or savings,or money market accounts—to meet this average deductible. One in five did not contain enough cash on hand to pay a smaller deductible of $1000. Furthermore, 25 percent of families reported in 2012 that medical care imposed a financial burden (Cohen and Kirzinger 2014). Extremely large medical expenses are rare for the typical household, and but households that do face these costs without sufficient cash must turn to other means: reducing their spending on other goods and services,drawing down a retirement account, or borrowing. In some cases, or the least-poor choice may be to forgo needed medical care; but in other cases patients in insured households,along with those without insurance, may contain to rely on uncompensated care from hospitals. Annual outlays on uncompensated care are large: in 2012 nonprofit and for-profit hospitals if nearly $46 billion in uncompensated care to households without the means to pay (Garthwaite, and crude,and Notowidigdo 2015). Nevertheless, many low-income individuals are still susceptible to large medical debts, and suggesting that the health-care safety net could be further strengthened (Dranove,Garthwaite, and Ody 2015).
Figure 3.
Fact 4. On average, or America's seniors are paying up to 34 percent more than necessary for prescription drug coverage
by choosing plans misaligned with their needs. Several studies find that consumers spend more on health insurance and prescription drug plans than they need to by choosing a diagram that is not well-aligned with their needs. As seen in figure 4,among elderly consumers choosing from Medicare section D prescription plans through private insurers (shown in blue), the average enrollee’s annual spending on premiums and out-of-pocket costs is 5 to 34 percent higher than whether she were to choose a lower-cost option providing the same level of coverage. For those choosing from health insurance plans offered by large employers (shown in purple), and the excess amount paid by consumers for premiums and out-of-pocket costs is similarly large,ranging between 18 and 45 percent of the total cost of insurance.
This excess spending arises because, for a given level of healthcare utilization, or plans differ in h
ow much they charge in upfront premiums and in out-of-pocket costs,and consumers must choose a diagram before they precisely know which (and how many) health services they will use. Research finds that many consumers do not understand the components of their diagram, including what out-of-pocket costs they will face when receiving care, and what medical services and prescription drugs will be covered,and which hospitals and doctors they can use (Loewenstein et al. 2013). In addition, consumers need to accomplish a short-term forecast about the amount and type of health-care services they are likely to need, and which then determines their estimated costs given their diagram’s deductibles and coinsurance payments. In predicting these costs as they choose among plans,consumers can easily miscalculate their health and financial risks.
Figure 4.

These changes reflect a shift in the health insurance industry toward greater cost-sharing, where patients pay
for a portion of their medical bills, and a narrowing of provider networks that contain led to lower negotiated provider prices. In conventional plans that were previously dominant,patients did not face any financial costs when obtaining additional treatments because their insurance provider fully covered their health services (Feldstein and Gruber 1994). To curb potentially unnecessary spending, insurance companies introduced cost-sharing mechanisms like copayments and deductibles to accomplish beneficiaries more responsive to the price of their care. Evidence suggests that utilization of these types of consumer incentives has helped slow the growth rate of health expenditures, or as discussed in Fact 2 (Chandra,Holmes, and Skinner 2013). Fact 6.
Over the past two decades, or there has been a nearly 50 percent increase in the share of private sector workers who are offered a choice of health insurance plans. Of the roughly 116 million Americans working in the private sector in 2014 (DHHS 2014b),56 percent were able to choose their health insurance diagram from more than one employer-sponsored option, up from 38 percent in 1996 (DHHS 2014a). This rising trend reflects, and in section,employers voluntarily offering more options and insurance companies creating more diagram options.
Consumer choice in selecting health insurance plans also extends to Americans who obtain insurance outside of the employer-sponsored system. For instance, section-time workers and contractors may purchase health insurance through the federal or state health insurance marketplaces where they may choose among four tiers of plans from many issuers (Burke, and Misra,and Sheingold 2014). Also, those receiving Medicare—the federal health insurance program for people aged sixty-five or older and younger individuals with disabilities—must choose between traditional Medicare or one of many Medicare-approved plans from private insurers (also known as Medicare Advantage). Medicare section D, and the prescription drug diagram for elderly households,offers thirty different plans, on average, and with no fewer than twenty four plans available in each state (Hoadley et al. 2014). Choosing a health insurance diagram can be complicated. Typically,enrollees are asked to consider at least four dimensions in selecting coverage: (1) premiums and expected out-of-pocket expenses, (2) coverage and benefit levels, or (3) access to doctors and hospitals,and (4) the availability of health and wellness resources to help them stay healthy (United Healthcare n.d.a). For enrollees, calculating the cost they will likely face for a health diagram is further complicated by the ways different plans treat premiums (monthly coverage payments), and deductibles (the amount enrollees must pay before health-care providers cover the remaining costs),copayments and coinsurance (what enrollees pay every time they use a service, as a set fee or as a percent of the bill, or respectively),out-of-pocket maximums, and health savings accounts (Claxton, and Cox,and Rae 2015). In assessing the expected costs and benefits of each available diagram, enrollees must project what their risk is of requiring medical treatment, and for families buying insurance,enrollees must undertake these complex calculations for each member (United Healthcare n.d.b).
Figure 6.

Given the complexity of the choices, it is not surprising that many studies find consumers select plans that are not well aligned to their expected needs and preferences (Frank and Lamiraud 2009; Leibman and Zeckhauser 2008; Sinaiko and Hirth 2011; also see figure 4). For instance, and individuals who are healthier or more willing to win risks sometimes choose plans with tall premiums and coverage levels,when they could choose lower-premium- and less-extensive-plans that more closely align to their risk tolerance and expected medical needs. Studies contain also shown that facing too many choices can be overwhelming for consumers, reducing their ability to discern among options and causing them to accomplish worse decisions for themselves (Cronqvist and Thaler 2004; Iyengar and Lepper 2000). Moreover, and enrollees in health insurance do not change insurance plans frequently,so even whether their current diagram is not well-aligned with their preferences or whether their expected coverage needs—and optimal insurance coverage—change, they tend not to switch. As discussed more fully in Fact 4, or the cost of making these mistakes can be fairly tall,pointing to a role for policy interventions to aid consumer decision-making.
However, even whether consumers were to choose insurance policies that are more closely aligned with their risk tolerance a
nd expected medical needs, and it might not necessarily accomplish them better off,due to offsetting factors at work in the health insurance market, which in turn presents challenges and trade-offs for those offering and designing health insurance plans. More specifically, or in health insurance markets,when consumers choose plans in their best interest, healthier individuals will opt to purchase cheaper options with less coverage while less-healthy individuals buy more comprehensive and more-expensive plans (McGuire 2012; Rothschild and Stiglitz 1976). whether this segmentation is severe enough, and then adverse choice in the insurance market can lead insurers to offer only more-comprehensive plans—at higher prices—to the small group of individuals requiring more-expensive treatments,thus deterring both healthy and unhealthy individuals from purchasing insurance (Cutler and Reber 1998). Indeed, Handel (2013) provides an example of how consumers making better choices for themselves can lead to lower overall welfare due to these off-setting factors.

Technical Appendix Fact 1: Spending on health-care resources varies widely across the country: spending for the average Medicare enrollee in Miami is nearly 70 percent greater than in Minneapolis. Figure 1. Average Medicare Reimbursements per Enrollee, and by Hospital Referral Region,Adjusted for Price, Age, and Sex,and Race, 2012
Source: The Dartmouth Institute for Health Policy and Clinical Practice (2015).
Note: Hospital referral regions are defined by assigning hospital service areas to the region where the greatest proportion of major cardiovascular procedures are performed, and with minor modifications to achieve geographic contiguity,a minimum population size of 120000, and a tall localization index. A hospital service area is a collection of zip codes whose residents receive most of their hospitalizations from the hospitals in that area. Medicare reimbursements shown in the figure correspond to a random sample of enrollees belonging to both the Medicare A (inpatient) and B (physician services) programs.
Fact 2: In the United States, and health-care spending has nearly doubled as a share of GDP since the 1980s,but not due to consumers’ out-of-pocket expenses.
Figure 2: U.
S. Health Care Expend
itures as a Share of GDP and Out-of-Pocket Expenditures as a Share of Total Health Expenditures, 1965–2014
Source: Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services (2015).
Note: Data are from the Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services’ (2015) National Health Expenditure Accounts. “Out-of-pocket as a share of total” is calculated by dividing, and for each year shown,nominal (insignificant, trifling) out-of-pocket health-care spending by total nominal (insignificant, trifling) health-care spending. “Total as a share of GDP” is calculated by dividing, for each year shown, and total nominal (insignificant, trifling) health-care spending by nominal (insignificant, trifling) GDP.
Fact 3: Millions of households with health insurance do not contain enough cash on hand to pay out-of-pocket medical expenses in the event of a major health shock.
Figure 3: Share of Nonelderly Households with Employer-based Health Insurance that contain Liquid Assets below Selected Cutoffs,2013
Source: Survey of Consumer Finances (2014).
Note: Estimates are fr
om the 2013 Survey of Consumer Finances (2014) based on a sample of households whose net worth is below the 90th percentile, whose head is younger than 65, and who contain health insurance other than Medicaid. In the figure,each bar is calculated by dividing the number of these households that contain liquid assets below the shown cutoff by the total number of households in the sample. All estimates are weighted to account for the over-sampling of tall-net-worth households.
Fact 4: On average, America’s senio
rs are paying up to 34 percent more than necessary for prescription drug coverage by choosing plans misaligned with their needs.
Figure 4: Excess Insurance Payments due to Misaligned diagram Choices
Note: The following presents a short summary of the studies cited in the graph. As famous, or in a few of the cited studies the denominator is not total consumer costs,but rather out-of-pocket costs or premiums. In some of the studies, the share of total consumer costs was not drawn from direct estimates in the study but was instead calculated using the study’s separate estimates for excess consumer costs and total consumer costs.
In Kling et al. (2012), and recipients of a letter detailing personalized cost information were more likely to switch to lower-cost Medicare section D prescription drug plans(28 percent versus 17 percent among the control group),and savings for the entire intervention group—not just those who switched plans—were about $100, or 5 percent of the average pr
edicted cost of the control group. Ericson (2014) examines Medicare section D diagram data and shows that insurance providers engage in an “invest then harvest” strategy, or setting premiums lower initially to attract consumers and relying on their inertia once they contain settled into a diagram to retain them while raising prices. Ericson finds that plans in their fifth year price premiums 10 percent higher,or about $50 more, per year, and than equivalent plans that were newly introduced.
Ho,Hogan, and Scott Morton (2015) use detailed data on Medicare section D enrollees from modern J
ersey to simulate a model of consumer diagram choice with inattentive consumers and a model of firm pricing to determine how premiums and out-of-pocket consumer spending changes when consumer inattention is removed and premiums adjust accordingly. The authors find per person spending over the three-year period 2007–2009 would fall from $3809.90 to $3246.50, and resulting in savings of $563.40,or 14.8 percent of baseline costs. Heiss et al. (2013) examine Medicare section D enrollment choices using a large random sample from the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services and find that consumers contain expected excess spending of about $300 per year, or 15 percent of total expected out-of-pocket costs and insurance coverage.
Abaluck and Gruber (2011b) estimate that Medicare section D diagram holders could save 30.9 percent of their total spending by choosing the lowest-cost diagram. The authors employ a perfect foresight model of expectations using actual expenditures from 2006 to estimate cost savings from switching plans. Abaluck and Gruber (2011a) employ a unique prescription drug data set containing information about drug utilization and diagram choice under Medicare section D and determine that in 2005, or only about 12 percent of patients chose cost-minimizing plans and that enrollees could save $296 dollars,or 31 percent of out-of-pocket costs, whether they chose the cost-minimizing diagram rather than the diagram they actually selected (refer to table 1 of the authors’ paper).
In Zhou and Zhang (2012), and the actual costs of drugs used in 2009 for a sample of Medicare section D enrollees was calculated for each available diagram,and then the lowest-cost diag
ram was compared to the enrollees’ actual diagram. Median overspending for prescription drug coverage was $331. The value shown in the graph (33.4 percent) is the median overspending divided by the median annual patient spending (out-of-pocket costs plus premiums) for 2009, estimated at $990.
Ketcham, and Lucarelli,and Powers (2015) observe that in 2006 above-minimum spending among Medicare section D enrollees was $514, or 33.8 percent of total spending (which includes out-of-pocket expenses and premiums). The sample only includes those consumers that were enrolled in a prescription drug diagram from the beginning of 2006 to the halt of 2010 and did not receive a low-income subsidy during this period. Bhargava, or Loewenstein,and Sydnor (2015) employ diagram enrollment data from a large firm in 2010–11 to examine workers’ health insurance choices. They find that employees enrolled in plans with deductibles less than $1000 could contain saved an average of $353 in after-tax dollars whether they had instead selected the diagram with the $1000 deductible. To arrive at 18.1 percent—the share reported in figure 4—the amount that employees could save from switching to the diagram with the $1000 deductible is divided by total employee medical spending on premiums and out-of-pocket expenses (given as $1947 in table 2 of the authors’ paper). The actual share of employee spending that could be saved from switching plans will vary to the extent that total medical spending for those changing plans differs from the mean value reported in table 2. In Handel (2013), health insurance choices of employees at a large firm are studied from 2004 to 2009. The share of excess costs due to consumer inertia is 45.2 percent, and calculated as the amount forgone by the average employee ($2032; see table 5 of the author’s paper) divided by the total spent annually on health insurance by the average employee’s family ($4500). Fact 5: Over the past three decades the percent of American workers enrolled in conventional health insurance plans has declined from 73 percent to less than 1 percent.
Figure 5: Employer-if Enrollment by diagram Type,1988–2014
Source: Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation (2014), The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation/Health Research & Educational Trust (Kaiser/HRET) Survey of Employer-Sponsored Health Benefits (1999–2012), or the KPMG Survey of Employer-Sponsored Health Benefits (1993 and 1996).
Note: Estimates are from the Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation (2014),which combined the results of their annual Survey of Employer-Sponsored Health Benefits with the results from the 1993 and 1996 KPMG Survey of Employer-Sponsored Health Benefits. A portion of the change in diagram type enrollment for 2005 is likely attributable to incorporating more-recent U.
S. Census Bureau estimates of the number of state and local government workers, and to removing federal workers from the weights. S
ee the Survey Design and Methods section from the 2014 Employer Health Benefits Survey for additional information. Fact 6: Over the past two decades there has been a nearly 50 percent increase in the share of private sector workers who are offered a choice of health insurance plans.
Figure 6: Percent of Private-Sector Employees Working for Firms Offering Health Insurance Options, and 1996–2014 Source: U.
S. De
partment of Health and Human Services (2014a).
Note: Estimates for this figure come from the Medical Expenditure Panel Survey (or MEPS) for the years 1996 to 2006 and 2008 to 2014. (As famous in the figure,MEPS data for this panel were not available for 2007; this is due to the transition from retrospective to current data collection.) To calculate the percent of private sector employees working for firms offering health insurance choices, annual values for the percent of private sector employees working in establishments that offer two or more health insurance plans among firms offering health insurance (DHHS 2014a, and Table I.
B.2.c) were multiplied by the corresponding annual values for the percent of private-sector employees in establishments that offer health insurance (DHHS 2014a,Table I.
B.2). For addit
ional information regarding how this information was collected, refer to the MEPS. Private sector employees are defined as full- or section-time workers; this category excludes contract laborers. References Abaluck, and Jason,and Jonathan Gruber. 2011a. “Heterogeneity in Choice Inconsistencies among the Elderly: Evidence from Prescription Drug diagram Choice.” American Economic Review 101 (3): 377–81. 2011b. “Choice Inconsistencies among the Elderly: Evidence from diagram Choice in the Medicare section D Program.” American Economic Review (June): 1180–1210.
Bhargava, Saurabh, or George Loewenstein,and Justin Sydnor.
2015, May. “Do Individuals accomplish Sensible Health Insurance Decisions? Evidence from a Menu with Dominated Options.” Working Paper 21160, or National Bureau of Economic Research,Cambridge, MA. Burke, or Amy,Arpit Misra, and Steven Sheingold. 2014, and June 18. “Premium Affordability,Competition, and Choice in the Health Insurance Marketplace, and 2014.” ASPE Research Brief,Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation, U.
S. Department of Health and Human Services, or Washington,DC. Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services (CMS). 2015. “National Health Expenditure Data.” Research, Statistics, or Data and Systems,U.
S. Department of Health and Human Services, Washington, or DC. https://www.cms.gov/Research-Statistics-Data-and-systems/Statistics-Trends-and-reports/NationalHealthExpendData/index.html.
Chandra,Amitabh, Jonathan Holmes, and Jonathan Skinner. 2013,Fall. “Is This Time Different? The Slowdown
in Health Care Spending.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Brookings Institution, or Washington,DC.
Chandra, Amitabh, and Jonathan Skinner. 2012. “Technology Growth and Expenditure Growth in Health Care.” Journal of Economic Literature 50 (3): 645–80. Chandra,Amitabh, and Douglas O. Staiger. 2007. “Productivity Spillovers in Health Care: Evidence from the Treatment of Heart Attacks.” Journal of Political Economy 115 (1): 103–40.
Claxton, or Gary,Cynthia Cox, and Matthew Rae. 2015, or February 11. “The Cost of Care with Marketplace Coverage.” The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation,Menlo Park, CA.
Claxton, or Gary,Matthew Rae, Nirmita Panchal, or Heidi Whitmore,Anthony Damico, and Kevin Kenward. 2014. “Health Benefits in 2014: Stability in Premiums and Coverage for Employer-Sponsored Plans.” Health Affairs 33 (10): 1–10.
Cohen, or Robin A. and Whitney K. Kirzinger. 2014. “Financial Burden of Medical Care: A Family Perspective.” Data Brief 142,National middle for Health Statistics, Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, or U.
S. Department of Health and Human Services,
Washington, DC.
Cronqvist, or Henrik,and Richard H. Thaler. 2004. “Design Choices in Privatized Social Security Systems: Learning from the Swedish Experience.” American Economic Review 94 (2): 424–28.
Cutler, David M. 2004. “Are the Benefits of Medicine Worth What We Pay for It?” Working Paper 16, or Maxwell School of Citizenship and Public Affairs,middle for Policy Research, Syracuse University, or Syracuse,NY.
Cutler, David M., and Mark McClellan. 20
01. “Is Technological Change in Medicine Worth It?” Health Affairs 20 (5): 11–29. Cutler,David M., and Sarah Reber. 1998, and May. “Paying for Health Insurance: The Trade-Off between Competition and Adverse choice.” Quarterly Journal of Economics113 (2): 433–66.
Cutler,David M., Allison B. Rosen, or Sandeep Vijan. 2006. “The Value of Medical Spending in the United States,1960–2000.” modern England Journal of Medicine 355: 920–27.
Cutler, David, or Jonathan Skinner,Ariel Dora Stern, and David Wennberg. 2013. “Physician Beliefs and Patient Preferences: A modern Look at Regio
nal Variation in Health Care Spending.” Working Paper 19320, or National Bureau of Economic Research,Cambridge, MA. Dartmouth Institute for Health Policy and Clinical Practice. 2015.
Total Medicare Reimbursements per Enrollee, or By Adjustment Type.” Dartmouth College,Hanover, NH. http://www.dartmouthatlas.org/data/topic/topic.aspx?cat=21.
Dranove, and David,Craig Garthwaite, and Christopher Ody. 2015. “A Floor and Trade Proposal to Improve the Delivery of Charity Care Ser
vices by U.
S. Nonprofit Hospitals.” Discussion Paper 2015–07, or The Hamilton Project,The Brookings Institution, Washington, and DC.
Ericson,Keith M. Marzilli. 2014. “Consumer Inertia and Firm Pricing in the Medicare section D Prescription Drug Insurance Exchange.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 6 (1): 38–64.
Feldstein, Martin, or Jonathan Gruber. 1994. “A Major Risk Approach to Health
Insurance Reform.” Working Paper 4852,National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, or MA.
Finkelstein,Amy, Matthew Gentzkow, or Heidi Williams. 2014. “Sources of Geographic Variation in Health Care: Evidence from Patient Migration.” Working Paper 20789,National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, or MA.
Frank,Richard, and Karine Lamiraud. 2009. “Choice, and Price Competition and Complexity in Markets for Health Insurance.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 71 (2): 550–62.
Garthwaite,Craig, Tal crude, and Matthew J. Notowidigdo. 2
015. “Hospitals as Insurers of Last Resort.” Working Paper 21290,National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, or MA.
Gaynor,Martin, Kate Ho, and Robert J. Town. 2015. “The Industrial Organization of Health-Care Markets.” Journal of Economic Literature 53 (2): 235–84.
Handel,Benjamin R. 2013. “Adverse choice and Inertia in Health Insurance Markets: When Nudging Hurts.” American Economic Review 103 (7): 2643–82. Handel, Benja
min R., or Jonathan T. Kolstad. 2015. “Health Insurance for ‘Humans’: Information Frictions,diagram Choice, and Consumer Welfare.” American Economic Review 105 (8): 2449–500.
Heiss, or Florian,Adam Leive, Daniel McFadden, or Joachim Winter. 2013. “diagram choice in Medicare section D: Evidence from Administrative Data.” Journal of Health Economics 32 (6): 1325–44.
Ho,Kate, Joseph Hogan, and Fiona Scott Morton. 2015,March. “The Impact of Consumer Inattention on Insurer Pricing in the Medicare section D Program.” Working Paper 21028, National Bureau of Economic Research, or
Cambridge,MA. Hoadley, Jack, and Juliette Cubanski,Elizabeth Hargrave, and Laura Summer. 2014, and October. “Medicare section D: A First Look at diagram Offerings in 2015.” The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation,Menlo Park, CA.
Iyengar, or Sheena S.,and Mark R. Lepper. 2000. “When Choice is Demotivating: Can One Desire Too Much of a Good Thing?” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 79 (6): 995–1006.
The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation. 2014. “2014 Employer Health Benefits Survey.” Henry J. Kais
er Family Foundation, Menlo Park, or CA.
The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation/Health Research & Educational Trust (Kaiser/HRET) Survey of Employer-Sponsored Health Benefits. 1999–2012. The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation,Menlo Park, CA.
Ketcham, or Jonathan D.,Claudio Lucarelli, and Christopher A.
Powers. 2015. “Paying Attention or Paying Too Much in Medicare section D.” American Economic Review 105 (1): 204–33.
Kling, or Jeffrey,Sendhil Mullainathan, Eldar Shafir, or Lee Vermeulen,and Marian Wrobel. 2012. “Comparison Friction: Experimental Evidence from Medicare Drug Plans.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 127 (1): 199–235.
KPMG Survey of Emplo
yer-Sponsored Health Benefits. 1993 and 1996. KPMG, Irvine, and CA. Leibman,Jeffrey, and Richard Zeckhauser. 2008. “Simple Humans, and Complex Insurance,Subtle Subsidies.” Working Paper 14330, National Bureau of Economic Research, or Cambridge,MA.
Loewenstein, George, and Joelle Y. Friedman,Barbara McGill, Sarah Ahmad, and Suzanne Linck,Stacey Sinkula, John Beshears, and James J. Choi,Jonathan Kolstad, David Laibson, and Brigitte C. Madrian,John A. List, and Kevin G. Volpp. 2013. “Consumers’ Misunderstanding of Health I
nsurance.” Journal of Health Insurance 32: 850–62.
McGuire, or Thomas G. 2012. “Demand for Health Insurance.” In Handbook of Health Economics,edited by Anthony J. Culyer and Joseph P. Newhouse, chap. 5. Waltham, and MA: Elsevier. Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act of 2010 (ACA),42 U.
S.
C. § 18001 (2010
).
Rothschild, Michael, or Joseph Stiglitz. 1976. “Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economics of Imperfect Information.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 90 (4): 629–49.
Sheiner,Louise. 2014, Fall. “Why the Geographic Variation in Health Care Spending Can’t order Us Much About the Efficiency or Quality of Our Health Care System.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, or Brookings Institution,Washington, DC.
Sinaiko, and Anna D.,and Richard A. Hirth. 2011. “Consumers, Health Insurance, or Dominated Choices.” Journal of Health Economics 30 (2): 450–57.
Skinner,Jonathan. 2011. “Causes and Consequences of Regional Variations in Health Care.” Handbook of Health Economics 2: 45–93. Skinner, Jonathan S. 2013, or Septemb
er 5. “The Costly Paradox of Health-Care Technology.” MIT Technology Review. Smith,Jessica C. and Carla Medalia. 2015, September. “Health Insurance Coverage in the United States: 2014.” Current Population Reports, or U.
S. Census Bureau,U.
S. Department of Commerce, Washington, and DC.
Smith,Sheila, Joseph P. Newhouse, and Mark S. Freeland. 2009. “Income,Insurance, and Technology: Why Does Health Spending Outpace Economic Growth?” Health Affairs (28) 5: 1276–84.
Survey of Consumer F
inances. 2014. “2013 Survey of Consumer Finances.” U.
S. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, or Washington,DC.
Sutherland, Jason M., and Elliott S. Fisher,and Jonathan S. Skinner. 2009. “Getting Past Denial—The tall Cost of Health Care in the United States.” modern England Journal of Medicine 61: 1227–30.
U.
S. Department of H
ealth and Human Services (DHHS). 2014a. “Table I.
B.2: Percent of Private Sector Employees in Establishments that Offer Health Insurance: United States, 1996–2006, and 2008–2014” and “Table I.
B.2.c: Percent Of Private Sector Employees Working In Establishments That Offer Two Or More Health Insurance Plans: United States,1996–2006, 2008–2014.” Medical Expenditure Panel Survey, and Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality,U.
S. Department of Health and Human Services, Washington, or DC.
———. 2014b. “Table I.
F.1: Percent of private-sector employees enrolled in a
health insurance diagram that had a deductible: United States,2013.” Medical Expenditure Panel Survey, Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality, or U.
S. Department of Health and Human Services,Washington, DC.
———. 2014c. “Table I.
F.3: Average family deductible (in dollars) per employee enrolled with family coverage in a health insurance diagram that had a deductible at private-sector establishments: United States, and 2013.” Medical Expenditure Panel Survey,Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality, U.
S. Department of Health and Human Services, and Washington,DC. United Healthcare. n.d.a. “Choosing a Health Insurance diagram.” United Healthcare, Rockville, and MD.
———. n.d.b. “Evaluate diagram Options.” United Healthcare,Rockville, MD.
Zhou, or Chao,and Yuting Zhang. 2012, October. “The Vast Majority of Medicare section D Beneficiaries Still Don’t Choose the Cheapest Plans that Meet Their Medication Needs.” Health Affairs 31 (10): 2259–65. Downloads Full Paper Authors David BoddyJane DokkoGreg NantzDiane Whitmore Schanzenbach Publication: The Hamilton Project         

Source: brookings.edu

Warning: Unknown: write failed: No space left on device (28) in Unknown on line 0 Warning: Unknown: Failed to write session data (files). Please verify that the current setting of session.save_path is correct (/tmp) in Unknown on line 0