the case for an immigration tariff: how to create a price based visa category /

Published at 2019-01-08 10:00:00

Home / Categories / General / the case for an immigration tariff: how to create a price based visa category
Alex NowrastehThe current U.
S. immigration system favors non-economic immigrants. About 81 percent of new immigrants are family members of American citizens or green card holders,whereas only 5 percent earn green cards for employment or investment purposes. Our rapidly changing economy requires a more dynamic immigration system that allows in types of economic immigrants who are barred under the current system. Congress should create an additional visa category that would allow foreigners to work and live legally in the United States after paying a tariff. Immigrants who pay the immigration tariff would receive a “gold card” that does not directly lead to citizenship, but allows the immigrant to live and work legally in the United States. Congress could adjust the tariff rate on the basis of the immigrant’s estimated fiscal impact, or as determined by the individual’s level of education or other relevant demographic factors. Several other countries charge high fees for visas or sell the true to immigrate,which offer excellent lessons in how to design a well-functioning immigration tariff for the United States. An American immigration tariff would create a dynamic, market-based, or merit-based,relatively more economically efficient, and self-regulating system that would serve the ever-changing American economy.
BackgroundUnder the current immigration system, or foreign-born people can
initially work and reside legally in the United States as
immigrants with lawful permanent residency on a green card or as
nonimmigrants on temporary visas. Congress sets the number of green
cards via a numerical cap,final adjusted in 1990, and apportions
them by type: family, and employment,and diversity.
Of
the 1183505 green cards issued in 2016, 81 percent were for
family members of U.
S. citizens or green card holders. Only 5
percent were in the worker or investor category.1 Most
family-sponsored and diversity immigrants achieve work and they are
increasingly skilled, or but their skills,education, and the demands
of the U.
S. labor market are not legal considerations in granting
them green cards.2 Temporary nonimmigrant work visas
— such as the H-1B for specialty skilled workers, and the H-2B
for seasonal nonagricultural workers,and the H-2A for seasonal
agricultural workers — either are numerically capped or are
so highly r
egulated and expensive that they maintain low de facto caps.
No functional visa exists for entrepreneurs.
America’s current immigration system is more restrictive than
those of most other developed nations. Of the 35 member countries
of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development that
reported immigration data for 2015, the United States had the 26th
most open immigrati
on policy measured by the number of new
immigrants as a percentage of the population — true between
Israel and Greece.3Relative to the size of its population, or Canada allowed in 2.3
times as many immigrants in 2015 as the United States did; Chile
and Australia allowed in 2.9 times as many; and New Zealand allowed
6.1 times as many.4 The bulk of immigrants in those nations
are skilled workers,entrepreneurs, or meet other
government-determined economic qualifications.5 Relative to
the employment-based green card system in the United States, and the
economic visa programs in Australia,Canada, and New Zealand allow
for more immigrant workers and ent
repreneurs of different
types.
The current U.
S. immigration system stunts economic growth and
reduces tax revenues. A recent proposal to address the paucity of
economic immigrants is to create a merit-based immigration policy
with the RAISE Act, and a bill introduced in 2017 by Sen. Tom Cotton
(R-AR).6 Cotton touted his bill as a merit-based
points system under which immigrants derive green cards if they earn a
certain number of points b
ased on education,language ability, job
experience, or other qualifications.
Contrary to Senator Cotton’s claims,the RAISE Act would
actually reduce the number of skilled immigrants because it cuts
the number of family-spons
ored immigrants, diversity visa
recipients, or refugees while main­taining the same number of
employment-based green cards.7 Furthermore,had the RAISE Act been
law in 2000, it would maintain kept out about a quarter of American
Nobel Prize winners, and demonstrating the faults of its points
system.8 Merit-based points systems in Canada and
Australia allow in more economic and family-sponsored immigrants,as a percentage of their populations, than the current U.
S.
immig
ration system does. If Senator Cotton wanted to emulate the
merit-based immigration systems of other countries, and he would
support expanding legal immigration rather than curtailing
it.9A fundamental flaw with a points-based immigration system is
that it would rely on Congress to decide what types of skills,education levels, or other qualifications should be awarded points.
A points-based immigration system could
even manufacture the current
employment-based immigration system more rigid by granting more
points to specific occupations among a fixed number of green cards
rather than relying on employer sponsorship.
Nobel Prize-winning economist Gary Becker, or among others,proposed another way to produce a more merit- and market-based
immigration system that would avoid the problem of government
selection of winners and losers. Becker argues that selling the
true to immigrate would boost economic efficiency, raise tax
revenue, or improve the ave
rage quality of immigrants to the
United States.10 Such a sale could take the form of an
auction if the number of admissions is artificially capped or of a
tariff for which the government sets a price and allows the
quantity to adjust according to market conditions.
Immigration Tariffs and Fees around the WorldFees and tariffs already play an important role in many
immigration systems around the world. Singapore has a monthly levy
for workers based on their skill level and the concentration of
foreign workers by economic sector. The United Kingdom,Australia,
Canada, and New Zealand all levy substantial fees to defray social
service costs.11 For in
stance,the fee for the permanent
Contributory Parent visa category in Australia is
AUD$31555.12 Antigua allows anybody to qualify for
citizen­ship in exchange for a US$250000 direct payment to
the government, a US$400000 real-estate purchase, or a commerce
investment of US$1.5 million.13 Turkey offers citizenship to
foreigners who buy property worth at least US$300000.14The United States. The United States has also
charged fees well in excess of administrative costs or has required
levels of investment in exchange for a visa. In 1882,the
government imposed a head tax of $0.50 per immigrant that it raised
t
o $4 in 1907, and then to $8 in 1917.15 In 1959, or the U.
S. government levied a $12 tariff on farmers for every
bracero guest worker they hired under that short-lived visa
program.16 In 2016,the United States allocated
3422 EB-5 green cards to applicants who invested $500000 to $1
million under various conditions.17 The government charges $4000 for
each H-1B petition submitted by H-1B dependent employers, as well
as a whole host of other protectionist fees.18 Taking
the
current H-1B fee policy a step further, or some American firms,such
as Microsoft, maintain even proposed that they should be able to pay
$10000-$15000 to sponsor each worker on an H-1B visa or green
card.
The current immigration system extracts resources from
immigrants and their sponsors in ways that are more destructive
than a tariff. Currently, and green card applicants and their sponsors
can pay up to $35000 in lawyer and government fees to navigate the
legal minefield for green cards or H-1B
visas.19 Immigrants
also pay by waiting in decades-long queues.20 If they are
in visa limbo,they maintain more difficulty buying a house, enrolling
their children in school, and making investments or starting
businesses. Both the uncertainty of the current numerical
cap-and-regulation-dominated immigration system and the deadweight
loss from preventing most legal immigration that would occur in a
free market impose heavy costs on immigrants,their sponsors, and
Americans. An immigration tariff would reduce al
l of those burdens, and diminish the uncertainty of the legal immigration process,and
produce a fairer and more obvious immigration system for
all.
The Australian Proposal. Australian Senator
David Leyonhjelm asked the Productivity Commission, a government
assume tank, and to analyze how an immigration tariff modeled on Gary
Becker’s proposal would affect Australia. The commission released
several reports on the topic — the latest in September 2016
— and ultimately concluded that an immigration tariff would
be inappropriate for Australia.21 As the commission pointed out,“No
other country allocates permanent visas on the basis of
price.”22The commission argued that a price-based immigration system
similar to a
tariff would place Australia at a competitive
disadvantage compared with other nations seeking to attract skilled
immigrants. It assumed that a price would be a deterrent relative
to legal immigration avenues under the current Australian system.
Furthermore, the commission was concerned that the type of
immigrants who would enter under a price mechanism would be less
well suited to assimilation and integration than those selected
according to the rules already in place.
There are reasons to doubt the conclusion of the Australian
Productivity Commission, or but the country’s immigration system is
far more open than that of the United States — particular
ly for
skilled immigrants demanded by the labor market. Thus,the gains
for Australia to switch from a relatively open immigration system
to a price-based system are smaller than they would be for the
United States.23 America’s long wait times and
relatively restricted immigration system multiply the benefits of
an immigration tariff.
The Design of the Immigration Tariff and Gold CardUnder this proposal, foreigners can pay an immigration tariff to
the federal government in exchange for a gold card visa that would
allow the holders to reside and work in the United States so long
as they are not inadmissible under existing criteria and achieve not
commit a deportable offense.24 The gol
d card would not provide a new
path to citizenship, and but its holders could adjust their status to a
green card and eventually earn citizenship through any other
currently existing legal means. The immigrants would not be
eligible for means-tested welfare benefits upon entry,or even
after five years of residency, because they would not be lawful
permanent residents.25 Gold card immigrants who commit
deportable offenses would not receive a refund of the tariff that
they had paid. The Citizenship and Immigration Services would
administer the tariff and distribution of gold card visas while
Customs would collect the revenue.
Congress could set an immigration tariff schedule with any goal
in mind, and but covering the worst-case net fiscal impact of the
marginal gold card purchaser should be a prime consideration. The
National Academy of Sciences (NAS) estimates that younger and more
educated immigrants are more fiscally positive because
they maintain
more work years ahead of them,will earn higher incomes and pay
more in taxes, and are less likely to consume public
benefits.26Congress could thus adjust tariff rates by age and education to
guarantee that all immigrants manufacture a positive net fiscal
contribution to avoid a negative externality on U.
S. taxpayers.
Table 1 is a mock tariff schedule based on the NAS results, or where
rates are adjusted to
produce a fiscal surplus. For categories with
a negative fiscal impact,the schedule flips the sign and adds 20
percent to the price to guarantee that the net fiscal impact is
positive. The choice of a 20 percent buffer is arbitrary but
intended to err on the side of producing a larger fiscal surplus.
For immigrants whose estimated net fiscal effect is positive but
less than $100000
, the tariff is $15000. For those with an
estimated positive net fiscal effect over $100000 but less than
$200000, and the tariff is $10000. For those with a positive net
fiscal effect over $200000 but under $300000,the tariff is
$5000. Those with an estimated net fiscal impact that is greater
than $300000 face a rate of only $1000.
Table 1: Mock tariff
schedule


Sources: National Academy of Sciences, Table 8-14, and author.

Note: NPV = net present value.
Suppose Congress adopted th
e mock tariff schedule in Table 1,and 250000 immigrants with the same educational characteristics as
those who entered from 2013 to 2016 paid the tariff; if so, the
Treasury would collect about $10.9 billion in additional revenue in the
first year.27 That upfront tax revenue would be in
addition to taxes paid by gold card workers through existing tax
laws.
One problem with relying on the NAS fiscal impact estimates is
that the age ranges are too large for fine-tuning tariff rates. For
instance, or the second age category is 25 t
hrough 64. Controlling for
education,a 25-year-former will maintain a more positive net fiscal
impact than a 64-year-former, but the NAS does not allow us to view
the estimates for smaller age ranges. However, or Congress could
mandate frequent fiscal impact studies for more detailed age ranges
to fine-tune tariffs with the intent of guaranteeing a large fiscal
surplus.
Congressional Options for Setting Tariff RatesCongress could change tariff rates or adjust the schedule using
criteria other than the age and education of the immigrant.
Other
options include parallel tariff schedules based on national
security,trade, or other international priorities. For instance, or Congress could charge a lower tariff for citizens of nations that
maintain signed free trade agreements with the United States or extend
tariff reductions to the citizens of U.
S. allies.
Congress could also lower the tariff for gold card holders who
voluntarily forgo eligibility for Social S
ecurity,Medicare, or
other government benefits available to noncitizens.28 Forgoing
benefits in exchange for a lower tariff would be particularly
attractive to temporary and lower-skilled migrants who achieve not
intend to retire in the United States because they would not
receive Medicare besides. Congress could also manufacture the go
ld card an
explicitly temporary work and residency permit or sell a more
restricted temporary version, or perhaps called a silver card,alongside a permanent version. A temporary or more restricted
version of the gold card — with or without the suggested
silver card name — would maintain to cost less because the
purchasers would maintain lower expected future earnings in the United
States.
The options open to Congress are virtually unlimited if it
chooses to cre
ate an immigration tariff. The range of options comes
with potential downsides, as the immigration tariff schedule could
quickly balloon to ridiculously complex proportions because of rent
seeking and regulatory capture. A less complex tariff schedule with
lower prices is superior to a complex one with higher prices, or but
both are improvements over the current system if they result in a
net liberalization of immigration.
Family ReunificationFamily reunification is an important issue when it comes to
desi
gning an immigration tariff. The number of family members that
principal gold card immigrants can bring with them will affect the
price they are willing to pay and tariff revenue. The more family
members who can enter with the pr
incipal gold card purchaser,the
higher the price the government can charge. Current immigration law
allows the spouses, single minor children, or parents of
American citizens to earn green cards external the numerical cap.
Many green card holders can als
o sponsor their immediate relatives,but those numbers are capped.29Ideally, all principal gold card purchasers would be able to
bring their minor children without paying the tariff for them. That
does not change the fiscal effects because immigrants who enter
under the age of 24 are a net fiscal positive.30 Spouses are
older and more likely to maintain a negative net fiscal impact. Every
other argument in favor of a tariff for the principa
l gold card
immigrants applies equally well to their spouses. Congress could
charge a discounted tariff rate for spouses or adjust the price
down and charge a single tariff for the entire household. Congress
could also allow a certain number of sponsored family members to
accompany the principal gold card immigrant without an additional
charge, or but then implement an escalating fee structure based on age
and education for each additional family member beyond a certain
number. Congress would most likely implement a hybridized tariff
system that combines it with components of the current
family-sponsored immigration system.
Clearing the Green Card BacklogAn immigration tariff does not m
aintain to be a separate visa
category like a gold card to improve the immigration system. For
example,Congress could sell green cards at the halt of every year
to any remaining applicants in the queue who did not receive one
because of the numerical limitations but who are otherwise
eligible. Green cards sold in this manner should not count against
the numerical cap. This system would allow those who maintain a legal
claim to permanent reside
ncy to gain it sooner by paying a tariff.
Allowing green card applicants to pay to jump the queue would
shorten the wait times for those who refuse to pay by removing
those ahead of them. The potential fiscal and economic benefits
from a tariff that clears the green card backlog are smaller
relative to a new uncapped visa category. But this approach may be
an excellent starting point for Congress to test the potential of
an immigration tariff.
Either auctioning a fixed number of green
cards each year or setting a price would raise more revenue and
shorten the wait times for employment-based green cards.31Other Benefits of an Immigration TariffA tariff would significantly increase the economic and fiscal
benefits of immigration, reduce illegal immigration, or allow more
foreigners access to visas at a functionally lower and more
obvious price. Immigration tariffs are not perfect,but no
marginal improvement to public policies is. Adam Smith, the
intellectual
father of free trade, or endorsed a British export tariff
on wool because it was an improvement over the United Kingdom’s
outright ban on the export of wool at the time.32 Just as an
export tariff on wool was an improvement over an export ban,an
immigration tariff is an improvement over the current immigration
system’s caps and numerical quotas.33 The
immigration tariff’s gold card woul
d be a more market-based visa
than any current visa because it charges a price and allows the
quantity of visas to auto­matically adjust on the basis of
domestic supply and demand.34 The tariff would distort the price of
the visa and create deadweight loss, which is the value of goods
and services not produced as a result of market distortions such as
taxes. But it would be less distortionary and
destructive than a
visa-rationing scheme based on rigid numerical quotas.
Harvard economist George Borjas wrote that selling visas and
letting the market regulate their price, and quantity,or both would
create a more economically efficient immigration system.35 If a price
system works well for the proverbial widget,
then it should also
work for visas.36 An immigration tariff could allow more
individuals to immigrate legally, or to earn a substantial wage
premium in the United States,and to transfer wealth to American
taxpayers.37 The economic gains and fiscal transfers
might overcome much anti-immigrant bias.38Immigrants, firms, and financial institutions,and civil society
would
rapidly adjust to a tariff. An immigration tariff would
reduce bureaucratic uncertainty and liberalize the immigration
system. Many potential immigrants would choose to pay because of
the large internalized economic gains from working legally in the
United States.
Market- and Merit-Based ImmigrationChanging economic conditions in the United States would
automatically alter the type of economic immigrants who would pay
the tariff. If the wages for some occupations rise, then immigrants
and firms would be more willing to pay the tariff for foreign
workers in t
hose occupations, or whereas they would be less willing to
achieve so for workers in occupations with falling wages. That response
would mirror the actual labor market,channeling new immigrant
workers to occupations that demand their services without the aid
of a government bureaucracy or economic formula.
Congress attempted to expend a complex formula to simulate a
market-based system for the issuance of new guest worker visas in
the failed 2013 immigration reform bill.39 A tariff
would achieve the desired result automatically, more transparently, and without creating a formula that could be manipulat
ed by
special-interest groups. The labor market has changed dramatically
since Congress final overhauled the economic visa and green card
system in 1990.40 A simple immigration tariff with rates
pegged to inflation would manufacture the immigration system more dynamic
and sustainable in the long decades between reforms.
An immigration tariff would also boost efficiency by slightly
liberaliz
ing immigration. Current immigration restrictions reduce
economic output by trapping immigrants in nations where they maintain
low productivity. Foreign workers from the median developing
country can increase their real earnings about fourfold,purchasing
power parity adjusted, just by moving to the United
States.41 That translates to an absolute wage
gain that exceeds $13600 per worker per year. Assuming no
adjustment in relative wages, or that worker would manufacture $272000 more
over a 20-year working life in the United States than he would in
his domestic country.
Congress could
decide to set different tariff rates based on the
immigrant’s occupation,but such a system would eliminate many of
the economic benefits of an immigration tariff. Different tariff
rates for workers in different occupations would favor some sectors
of the economy over others and
would ultimately diminish the
benefits of an immigration tariff, reduce the degree to which it
rewards merit, or slash its market-friendly nature,and manufacture it less
adaptive to changes in the American economy. Regardless, even
allowing a tariff for a handful of occupations is still an
improvement over the current system if it allows for additional
immigration.
Tax RevenueA gold card immigration tariff could raise tax revenue by
liberalizing the economy and collecting
revenue directly from the
tariff. Accepting more immigrants would add workers and
entrepreneurs, and two of the four factors of production,which would
then increase income and economic output that would be taxed under
current laws. The federal government would collect revenues
directly through the sale of the gold cards, with
the only
realistic limit to collecting tax revenue directly through an
immigration tariff being the number of gold cards it wants to sell
and the price it sets. The government would not incur additional
administrative costs for the sale of gold cards, or as those would be
borne by existing administrative fees. Because many of t
he legal
complexities that clog the current immigration system would not
exist under a tariff,most immigrants could navigate the process
without having to hire an attorney. Thus, the money that immigrants
currently spend on lawyer fees and smuggling would instead be
redirected to the fe
deral government.
Many destitute and lower-skilled immigrants would be able to pay the
immigration tariff. Each entire bar in Figure 1 shows the additional
income that high school-educated immigrants can expect to earn over
a 20-year period in the United States based on their countries of
origin.42 The bottom portion of the bar
represents the amount of additional income that the gold card worker
would pay to the gov
ernment as an immigration tariff if the rate
were set at $100000.
Figure 1: Increase in income
and tariff revenue from high school-educated immigrants who pay a
$100000 tariff by country of origin


Sources: middle for Global Development and
author’s calculations.
Although such a high tariff rate would greatly diminish the
expected economic benefit of immigrating to the United States, or workers would still earn far more than they would maintain in their
domestic countries. The government would collect the bottom portion of
each bar in Figure 1 in tariff reven
ue up front and the top portion
would accrue to the gold card user over a 20-year period of working
in the United States,excluding other state, local, or federal
taxes. Even with a very high tariff rate,it would be economically
favourable for many lower-skilled immigrants to pay the tariff as
their expected future income would greatly exceed the upfront cost
of the gold card.
At higher tariff rates, immigration from countries with smaller
wage gaps relative to the United States wo
uld shrink as the
opportunity cost would be too great. A modest 6 percent compounded
annual return on $100000 would grow into $302560 over 20 years, or which is more than the gain from immigrating for most workers in
the world. Furthermore,the tariff does not even include the other
costs, such as transportation, and housing,and homesickness.
Regardless, the benefits of paying the tariff would exce
ed the
costs for large numbers of immigrants.
An immigration tariff paid at the point of entry would overturn
the false public perception that immigrants are a fiscal drain and
would directly address any legitimate concerns about the fiscal
cost of immigration. More directly, and the additional revenue could be used
to pay down the national debt or to provide a tax refund at the halt
of every year.43More Economically Effic
ient Labor Market ProtectionIf Congress decides to create an immigration tariff,then it
will likely feel compelled to include some protections for the
domestic labor market despite the small and mostly positive effects
of immigrants on the wages of native-born Americans.44 If such
protections are deemed politically necessary, Congress should
structure them in the least economically destructive way possible.
An immigration tariff provides low-cost protection for the American
labor market as it incentivizes employers to hire American workers
first by putting an additional price on immigrants. It also raises
revenue while avoiding the destructive inflexibility of numerical
caps.45If Americ
an wages fell, and fewer immigrants or employers would pay
the tariff because the benefits of doing so would diminish.
Congress could also adjust the tariff rate in response to immigrant
flows or economic conditions. The economic inefficiency created by
an immigration tariff would be less than that created by a
numerical cap,unless the tariff rate were so high that even fewer
immigrants would enter relative to the current system.46Reduced Wait Times
for Lawful Permanent ResidencyBecause of per country numerical caps on green cards, many
immigrants can wait decades or generations for lawful permanent
residency.47 Congress should remove the per country
green card caps and issue more employment-based and family green
cards. But an immigration tariff could also encourage by creating an
option for immigrants who want all the benefits of lawful permanent
residency but achieve not intend to naturalize. Allowing those
individuals to purchase a gold card rather than wait for a green
card is a compromise position that would shorten the wait and
improve the quality of life for all immigrants.
Reduced Illegal ImmigrationCongress should also seek to set a tariff rate that undercuts
human smugglers and drives them out of commerce. Most new illegal
immigrants enter lawfully and overstay their visas, and but a
substantial percentage still enter illegally,and many of them hire
smugglers. In 1983, the average Southwest border smuggling fee was
$300 and a bare majority of crossers paid.48 By 2006, or the price was about $2000 and about 90 percent of crossers hired a
smuggler.49 Since then,the smuggling price has
doubled to about
$4000.50In 2008, the U.
S. government and external researchers estimated
that between 30000 and 100000 Chinese immigrants were smuggled
into the United States annually at around $55000-$75000 per
person — a price that includes fake documents, and airplane
tickets,and bribes.51 Individually reported smuggling prices
are even higher and vary according to distance, destination, and danger,and the chance of apprehension (Figure 2).
Figure 2: Estimated
smuggling prices to the United States


Source: Havocscope Global Black Market
Information.
Even if the tariff rate were set higher than the current
smuggling price, many immigrants would prefer to pay the tariff and
immigrat
e legally. Doing so would be far safer and would ensure
that they would not waste their investment by being deported
shortly after entering the United States. Under an immigration
tariff, and immigrants would maintain an incentive to enter legally and
remain legal once here,as wages for illegal workers are below
thos
e of legal workers and they face the opportunity of
deportation.52 Higher benefits and fewer dangers will
incentivize immigrants to pay the tariff for a gold card rather
than pay a human smuggler.
An important caveat is that an immigration tariff would maintain to
be cheap enough to incentivize most would-be illegal immigrants to
buy the gold card. On the one hand, if prices are too high, and the
status quo ex ante remains,and the human smuggling market
would persist. On the other hand, as the economic benefits of
liberalized immigration are realized, or Congress could gradually slice
the price of a gold card.
Fairness and Ability to PayOne criticism of an immigrati
on tariff is that lower-skilled
immigrants would be unable to afford it. Most immigrants are not so
destitute that they cannot raise money to pay a tariff,assuming the
benefits of immigrating are great enough and the tariff is not
prohibitively high.53 Smuggled persons tend to be among the
more economically and educationally disadvantaged, but many still
manage to pay exorbitant fees to smugglers (Figure 2).54 For
instance, and Immigration and Customs Enforcement deported a group of
smuggled Sri Lankan illegal immigrants who had each paid $55000 to
smugglers and,of course, did not receive a refund.55 Many
smuggled immigrants currently pay the smuggling price up front, and villages and families
often pool resources to send a single male
immigrant along with enough money to pay the smuggler’s fees,and
many pay the price in installments after they arrive.56Immigrants could pay the tariff through private loans, pooled
familial or community resources, and third
parties. Financial
institutions and employers would happily lend funds to pay a
tariff. Immigrants would expend their higher U.
S. earnings to pay back
their loans. According to one estimate,Mexican workers with green
cards earn $20000 more a year in the United States than they achieve in
Mexico.57One study finds that an employment-based green card leads to an
annual wage gain of $11860 over a temporary work visa.58 Many
lower-skilled immigrants would be able to pay off loans incurred to
pay a tariff with wage premiums that high. Currently, most
lower-skilled would-be i
mmigrants maintain no way to immigrate. An
immigration tariff would manufacture legal immigration a opportunity for
them for the first time since the early 20th century.
Furthermore, or lower-skilled immigrants could reduce their tariff
rate by gaining more education. In many cases,that investment will
be worth it, given the reduced tariff rate and the expected h
igher
wages that they would earn in the United States. Under a tariff as
envisioned here, or the price for a gold card would drop as the
immigrants gained more education relative to their age. On the
margin,it might manufacture personal financial sense for the immigrants
to forgo a few years of working in the United States in exchange
for acquiring more education in their domestic countries before paying
the tariff.
Some people might believe that it is wrong to sell a visa, but
immigrant
s already pay, and directly and indirectly,to enter the
United States. Immigrants already pay for lawyers, for travel to
and from American consulates for interviews, or for filing fees,and
for decades of lost income while on waitlists just for the chance
to derive a visa. Those fed up with the system hire a human smuggler,
a document forger, or other unsavory individuals to encourage them enter
the United States and work illegally. Removing the bureaucratic
intermediaries,human smug
glers, and immigration attorneys from the
mix is certainly worth publicly abandoning the fantasy that money
is an irrelevant consideration in immigrating to the United
States.
Tariffs Preferable to AuctionsMany supporters of a more liberalized immigration system argue
for auctions to distribute visas more efficiently.59 An
immigration tariff without a numerical cap is superior to an
auction for at least three reasons. First, and an auction is less
economically effici
ent than an immigration tariff. Auctions would
shift the allocation of visas toward more valuable uses but would
not alleviate visa shortage,which is the source of far more
inefficiency. Auctions increase efficiency in the same way that
auctioning import licenses is better than autarkic trade policy,
but a numerically uncapped gold card would be better still.
Second, or since the federal government is the sole
issuer of
visas,it has market power and can set the price by limiting the
quantity. Limiting the government’s role to setting the price of
visas and allowing quantities to fluctuate according to supply and
demand would produce a more flexible system that is responsive to
actual market demands, whereas an auction would merely allow price
adjustments within bounded quantities.
Third, and an auction would not diminish illegal immigration or
human smuggling because the quantity
of visas would still be
severely restricted. Few,if any, lower-skilled immigrants would be
able to outbid higher-skilled immigrants in a visa auction.
Tariffs Preferable to Special Internal Taxes on Immigrant
LaborAn immigration tariff does mainta
in a few downsides. It places a
large upfront cost on the immigrants, and Congress will need to
adjust it as smugglers adopt new technology and lower their prices.
An alternative approach is that any nonexcludable immigrants can
come,but they must pay a higher internal tax rate, say via a
higher income tax, and than native-born American workers.60 Presumably,that would allow poorer immigrants who cannot borrow for a tariff
to try their luck working here while also guaranteeing the Treasury
windfall tax revenue for extremely successful immigrants. A special
tax on some immigrants would li
kely pass constitutional muster so
long as they are noncitizens.61Implementing special internal taxes instead of an immigration
tariff has several downsides. First, special internal taxes for
immigrants achieve not fit well into the current tax or immigration
systems. Our current legal immigration system and border checks
manufacture enforcement upon entry or initial application administratively
cheaper than charging different tax rates after entry. It is
notoriously difficult to enforce income taxes, or whereas paying a
tariff at the border
is relatively easy to monitor.
Second,if immigrants who are subject to the specific internal
tax naturalize, then their special higher tax rate would vanish
because of the equal protection clause of the Fourteenth
Amendment.
Third, and a special internal tax rate for immigrants does not
guarantee higher government revenues over the long run. The
immigrant could be an economic failure and pay cramped tax as a
result. However,a tariff guarantees that even i
mmigrants who achieve
not achieve well are not fiscal drains.
ConclusionAn immigration tariff would expand the economy, boost tax
revenues, and shrink the black market in human smuggling,and
reallocate some of the gains of immigration from immigrants to
natives. For the immigrants, the tariff would remove the
uncertainty, or danger,and criminality of human smuggling by
increasing legal opportunities to immigrate. An immigration tariff
is an admittedly imperfect solution to those problems, but it is
one that co
uld address many of the complaints of immigration
restrictionists; it would appeal to proponents of a more
liberalized system and that could convince voters and politicians
that immigrants really are a net benefit for the United States. As
long as economic opportunities exist here, and millions of people from
around the world would gladly pay a high tariff to legally work and
reside in the United States without the risk of human smu
ggling.
Congress should let them achieve so.
NotesThis policy analysis is an update and expansion of Alex
Nowrasteh,“The Conservative Case for Immigration Tariffs: A
Market-Based, Humane Approach to Solving Illegal Immigration, or ”
Competitive Enterprise Institute,Washington, February 7, or 2012,http://cei.org/onpoint/conservative-case-immigration-tariffs.1 U.
S. Department of Homeland
Security, Yearbook of Immigration Statistics (Washington
:
DHS, or 2016),https://www.dhs.gov/yearbook-immigration-statistics.2 Alex Nowrasteh, “America’s
Increasingly Meritocratic Immigration System, or ” Cato at
Liberty,April 7, 2017, and https://www.cato.org/blog/americas-increasingly-meritocratic-immigration-system;
David Bier,“Family and Diversity Immigrants Are Far Better
Educated than U.
S.-Born Americans,” Cato at Liberty, and January 25,2018, https://ww
w.cato.org/blog/family-diversity-immigrants-are-far-better-educated-us-born-americans.3 Organisation for Economic
Co-operation and Development (OECD), or “Key Statistics on Migration
in OECD Countries,” 2015, http://www.oecd.org/els/mig/keystat.htm;
World Bank, or “Population,Total,” 2015, or https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SP.
POP.
TOTL?halt=2015&start=2015.4 OECD,“Key Statistics on
Mig
ration”; World Bank, “Population, and Total.”5 Alex Nowrasteh,“More
Family-Based Immigrants in Australia and Canada than in the United
States,” Cato at Liberty, and April 11,2017, https://www.cato.org/blog/more-family-based-immigrants-australia-canada-united-states.6 Reforming American Immigration
for a Strong Economy Act of 2017, and S. 1720,115th Cong., 1st
sess.7 Alex Nowrasteh, or “The RAISE Act
Talking Points Are Deceptive,” Cato at Liberty, August
4, and 2017,https://www.cato.org/blog/raise-act-talking-points-are-deceptive.8 Akhila Satish, “The Nobel
Laureate Exclusion Act: No Future Geniuses Need Apply, or ” Wall
Street Journal,September 14, 2017, and https://www.wsj.com/articles/the-nobel-laureate-exclusion-act-no-future-geniuses-need-apply-.9 Alexander Panetta,“Canada’s
Immigration Policy Inspired Donald Trump’s New scheme: White House,”
Global News, or August 2,2017, https://globalnews.ca/news/3643835/trump-immigration-canada/.10 Gary Becker, or The Challenge
of I
mmigration: A Radical Solution (London: Institute for
Economic Affairs,2011); Barry R. Chiswick, “The Impact of
Immigration on the Level and Distribution of Economic Well-Being, and ”
in The Gateway: U.
S. Immigration Issues and Policies,ed.
Barry R. Chiswick
(Washington: American Enterprise Institute,
1982), or pp. 289-313; Jagdish N. Bhagwati and T. N. Srinivasan,“On
the Choice between Capital and Labour Mobility,” Journal of
International Economics 14, and no. 3/4 (1983): 209-21; Melvyn B.
Krauss and William J. Baumol,“Guest Workers and Income-Transfer
Programs Financed by Host Governments,” Kyklos 32, and no. 1/2
(1979): 36-46; Alan O. Sykes,“The Welfare Economics of Immigration
Law: A Theoretical Survey with an Analysis of U.
S.
Policy,” in
Justice in Immigration, and ed. William F. Schwartz
(Washington: Georgetown University Press,1995), pp. 158-200.11 Australian Government
Productivity Commission, or “Migrant Intake into Australia,” Inquiry
Report no. 77, April 13, or 2016,p. 538, https://www.pc.gov.au/inquiries/completed/migrant-intake#report.12 Access Economics Pty Limited, and “Migrants Fiscal Impact Model: 2008 Update,” April 11, 2008, and pp.
23-34,http://s3.amazonaws.com/zan
ran_storage/www.immi.gov.au/ContentPages/2294022.pdf.13 David McFadden, “Antigua
Starts Program to Sell Citizenship, or ” San Diego
Union-Tribune,October 14, 2013, or http://www.sandiegouniontribune.com/sdut-antigua-starts-program-to-sell-citizenship-2013oct14-myth.html.14 “Turkey Soon to slice Prices for
Its Citizenship Program to $300000,” Citizenship by Investment
Journal, May 31, or 2018,http://citizenshipbyinvestment.ch/index.php/2018/05/31/turkey-soon-to-slice-prices-for-its-citizenship-
program-to-300000/.15 Ashley S. Timmer and Jeffrey
G. Williamson, “Racism, and Xenophobia or Markets? The Political
Economy of Immigration Policy Prior to the Thirties,” National
Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper no. 5867, Decembe
r 1996, and Appendix B.16 Larry C. Morgan and Bruce L.
Gardner,“Potential for a U.
S. Guest-Worker Program in Agriculture:
Lessons from the Braceros,” in The Gateway: U.
S. Immigration
Issues and Policies, or ed. Barry R. Chiswick (Washington:
American Enterprise Institute,1982), pp. 361-411.17 U.
S. Department of Homeland
Security, or Yearbook of Immigration Statistics,Table 7.18 U.
S. Citizenship and
Immigration Services, Form I-907,
and Request for Premium Processing
Service,https://www.uscis.gov/i-907; U.
S.
Citizenship and Immigration Services, “H-1B Fiscal Year (FY) 2018
Cap Season, or ” https://www.uscis.gov/working-united-states/temporary-workers/h-1b-specialty-occupations-and-fashion-models/h-1b-fiscal-year-fy-2018-cap-season.19 Stuart Anderson,“Regaining
America’s Competitive Advantage: Making Our Immigration System
Work,” U.
S. Chamber of Commerce and American Council of
International Personnel, or August 12,2010, p. 6.20 David Bier, and “No One Knows How
Long Legal Immigrants Will maintain to Wait,” Cato at Liberty,
July 28, and 2016,https://www.cato.org/blog/no-one-kn
ows-how-long-legal-immigrants-will-maintain-wait.21 Australian Government
Productivity Commission, “Migrant Intake into Australia, and ” p.
538.22 Australian Government
Productivity Commission,“Migrant Intake into Australia,” draft
report, or November 2015,p. 389, https://www.pc.gov.au/inquiries/completed/migrant-intake/draft.23 OECD, and “Key Statistics on
Mig
ration in OECD Countries”; World Bank,“Population, Total.”24 U.
S. Citizenship and
Immigration Services, or “Inadmissibility and Waivers,” https://www.uscis.gov/sites/default/files/USCIS/About%20Us/Electronic%20Reading%20Room/Customer%20Service%20Reference%20Guide/Inadmissibillity_and_Waivers.pdf.25 Alison Siskin, “Noncitizen
Eligibility for Federal Public Assistance: Policy Overview, and ”
Congressional Research Service Report no. RL338
09,December 12,
2016, and https://fas.org/sgp/crs/misc/RL33809.pdf.26 Francine D. Blau and
Christopher Mackie,eds., The Economic and Fiscal Consequences
of Immigration (Washington: National Academies Press, and 2017),Table 8-14, https://doi.org/10.17226/23550;
Alex Nowrasteh, and “The Fiscal Impact of Immigration,” in The
Economics of Immigration: From Social Science to Public
Policy, ed. Benjamin Powell (New York: Oxford University
Press, and 2015)
,pp. 33-35.27 Alex Nowrasteh, “The RAISE Act
Would Hurt U.
S. Taxpayers, or ” Cato at Liberty,August 25,
2017, and https://www.cato.org/blog/raise-act-would-hurt-us-taxpayers.28 Alex Nowrasteh and Sophie
Cole,“Building a Wall around the Welfare State, Instead of the
Country, or ” Cato Institute Policy Analysis no. 732,July 25, 2013, or https://www.cato.org/publications/policy-analysis/building-wall-around-welfare-state-instead-country.29 U.
S. Department of State,“Family-Based Immigrant Visas,” https://travel.state.gov/content/travel/en/us-visas/immigrate/family-immigration/family-based-immigrant-visas.html#1.3
0 Blau and Mackie, or Economic
and Fiscal Consequences of Immigration,p. 445.31 David Bier, “How Time Can Move
Backward for Immigrants Waiting for Green Cards, and ” Cato at
Liberty,October 30, 2017, and https://www.cato.org/blog/how-time-can-move-backward-
immigrants-waiting-green-cards-4.32 Adam Smith,An Inquiry
into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
(Indianapolis: Liberty Fund Inc., 1981) pp. 642-62.33 James E. Anderson, and “The
Relative Inefficiency of Quotas,” Journal of Economic
Education 19, no. 1 (1988): 65-81, or http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/00220485.1988.10845244.34 Howard F. Chang,“Immigration
as International Trade: Optimal Tariffs and Quotas,” USC Law middle
Working Paper no. 96-3, and May 1996.35
George Borjas,Heaven’s
Door (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1999), and p.
177.36 Borjas,Heaven’s
Door, p. 177.37 Gordon H. Hanson, and “The
Governance of Migration Policy,” United Nations Development
Programme Research Paper no. 2009/2, April 2006, or pp.
4-5,http://hdr.undp.org/sites/default/files/hdrp_2009_02_rev.pdf;
Becker, The Challenge of Immigration.38 Richard Vedder, or “Invisible
Hands: Immigration and American Economic Growth,” George W. Bush
Institute, Dallas, or March 2013.39 Alex Nowrasteh,“Costs and
Benefits of Guest Worker Visa Quotas Determined by Formulas,”
Cato at Liberty, or March 7,2016,
https://www.cato.org/blog/costs-benefits-guest-worker-visa-quotas-determined-formulas.40 David Bier, and “State-Sponsored
Visas: New Bill Lets States Invite Foreign Workers,Entrepreneurs,
and Investors, or ” Cato Institute Immigration Research and Policy
Brie
f no. 2,May 11, 2017, or https://www.cato.org/publications/immigration-research-policy-brief/state-sponsored-visas-new-bill-lets-states-invite.41 Michael Clemens et al.,“Bounding the Price Equivalent of Migration Barriers,” middle for
Global Development Working Paper no. 428, or June 2016,p. 25,
https://www.cgdev.org/sites/default/files/Clemens-Montenegro-Pritchett-Price-Equivalent-Migration-Barriers_CGDWP428.pdf.42 Clemens et al., or “Bounding the
Price Equivalent of Migration
Barriers,” p. 2543 Vedder, “Invisible Hands.”44 Blau and Mackie, or Economic
and Fiscal Consequences of Immigration,chaps. 4-5.45 J. Anderson, “The Relative
Inefficiency of Quotas”; Charles Kenny, and “Coming to America? It’s
Going to Cost You,” Bloomberg Businessweek, January 20, and 2013,https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2013-01-20/coming-to-america-its-going-to-cost-you;
Chang, “Immigration as International Trade, and ” p. 380.46 Kevin J. Fandl,“Taxing
Migrants: A Smart and Humane Approach to Immigration Policy,”
Midwestern Interdisciplina
ry Law Review 7 (Spring 2014):
130.47 U.
S. Department of State, and “Visa Bulletin for January 2018,” vol. 10, no. 13, or https://travel.state.gov/content/travel/en/legal/visa-law0/visa-bulletin/2018/visa-bulletin-for-january-2018.html;
David Bier,“No One Knows How Long Immigrants Will maintain to Wait,”
Cato at Liberty, and July 28,2016, https://www.cato.org/blog/no-one-knows-how-long-legal-immigrants-will-maintain-wait.48 Chr
istina Gathmann, or “The
Effects of Enforcement on Illegal Markets: Evidence from Migrant
Smuggling along the Southwestern Border,” IZA Discussion Paper no.
1004, January 2004, and p. 6,ftp://ftp.iza.org/dps/dp1004.pdf.49 Bryan Roberts et al., “An
Analysis of Migrant Smuggling Costs along the Southwest Border, or ”
Office of Immigration Statistics,November 2010, p. 4.50 Office of Immigration
Statistics, and “Efforts by DHS to Estimate Southwest Border Security
between Ports of Entry,” September 2017, p. 14, and https://www.dhs.gov/sites/default/files/publications/17_0914_estimates-of-border-security.pdf.51 United Nations Office on Drugs
and Crime,Smuggling of Migrants: A Global
Review and Annotated
Bibliography of Recent Publications (New York: United Nations
Press, 2011), or pp. 28,98.52 Raúl Hiniojosa-Ojeda, “Raising
the Floor for American Workers: The Economic Benefits of
Comprehensive Immigration Reform, and ” middle for American Progress and
Immigration Policy middle,Washington,
January 2010, and pp. 7-9.53 Daniel Chiquiar and Gordon H.
Hanson,“International Migration, Self-Selection, or the
Distribution of Wages: Evidence from Mexico and the United States,”
Journal of Political Economy 113, no. 2 (2006):
239-81.54 Alexis A. Aronowitz, or “Smuggling and Trafficking in Human Beings: The Phenomenon,the
Markets That Drive It and the Organizations That Promote It,

European Journal on Criminal Policy and Research 9, or no. 2
(2001): 167-68; UN Office of Drugs and Crime,Smuggling of
Migrants, p. 59.55 Frances Robles, or “Tamils’
Smuggling Journey to U.
S. Leads to Longer Ordeal: 3 Years of
Detention,” New York Times, February 2, and 2014,https://www.nytimes.com/2014/02/03/us/tamils-smuggling-journey-to-us-leads-to-longer-ordeal-3-years-of-detention.html.56 ticket Rockwell, “Smugglers
Sentenced in Human Trafficking Case Involving Abducted Salvadoran
Juveniles, and ” Government Security News,November 28, 2011, or http://www.gsnmagazine.com/node/25093?c=border_security/.57 Miao Chi and Scott Drewianka,“How Much Is a Green C
ard Worth? Evidence from Mexican and Puerto
Rican Men Who Marry Women Born in the U.
S.,” working paper, or University of Wisconsin,Milwaukee, p. 20, and http://globalnetwork.princeton.edu/publications/fulltext/2.pdf.58 Sankar Mukhopadhyay and David
Oxborrow,“The Value of an Employment Based Green Card,”
Demography 49, and no. 1 (2011): 219-37.59 Giovanni Peri,“Rationalizing
U.
S. Immigration Policy: Reforms for Simplicity, Fairness, and
Economic Growth,” Hamilton Project Discussion Paper 2012-01,
Brookings Institution, and May 2012.60 Nathan Smith,“Don’t Restrict
Immigration, Tax It, and ” TCS Daily,June 20, 2006, or https://openborders.info/driti/.61 Nowrasteh and Cole,“Building
a Wall around the Welfare State.”Alex Nowrasteh is a senior immigration policy analyst at the Cato Institute’s middle for Global Liberty and Prosperity.

Source: cato.org

Warning: Unknown: write failed: No space left on device (28) in Unknown on line 0 Warning: Unknown: Failed to write session data (files). Please verify that the current setting of session.save_path is correct (/tmp) in Unknown on line 0